logo

60 pages 2 hours read

Nassim Nicholas Taleb

Fooled By Randomness: The Hidden Role of Chance in Life and in the Markets

Nonfiction | Book | Adult | Published in 2001

A modern alternative to SparkNotes and CliffsNotes, SuperSummary offers high-quality Study Guides with detailed chapter summaries and analysis of major themes, characters, and more.

Epilogue-PostscriptChapter Summaries & Analyses

Epilogue Summary: “Solon Told You So”

Taleb provides an update on Nero’s status. He has recovered from his cancer, and he continues to make great gains in the market. Nero lives in London and contends with horrendous traffic during his daily commute. Rather than take the train, Nero decides to indulge himself. He acquires a license to fly a helicopter instead. Even though Nero carefully analyzes probability and risk in his work, he does not seem to pay equal attention to differences in physical risk between operating a car and a helicopter. Nero crashes his helicopter and dies.

Postscript Summary: “Three Afterthoughts in the Shower”

In the first postscript, Taleb considers what he calls the inverse skills problem. He defines it as the phenomenon whereby the CEO of a company exhibits fewer hard skills than those lower on the company ladder. He classifies skills by presenting a cook as an example. If the cook is incompetent, the result is immediately noticeable in the poor quality of the food they produce. If a CEO is incompetent, the direct correlation to results is more difficult to determine. Taleb implies that what makes a CEO rise to the position has more to do with political savvy than skill. He distinguishes between CEOs and entrepreneurs, noting that the latter demonstrate the full gamut of quantifiable skills. Taleb suggests that randomness plays a crucial role in a CEO’s success, which depends on results rather than processes. Taleb also draws an equivalent between CEOs and elected political officials, arguing that the “contributions of civil servants might be even more difficult to judge than those of the executives of a corporation—and the scrutiny is smaller” (295).

In his second afterthought, Taleb explores “additional benefits of randomness” (296). He begins by asking the reader to imagine a hypothetical scenario in which they attend a dinner in New York City with a suburban commuter. The commuter is so preoccupied with the train schedule that they do not enjoy the dinner, and in this scenario, they cut it short to catch the train. Taleb proposes a modification to the scenario: If the train schedule were less rigid and more random, what would the effect be on the commuter be? Likely, the commuter would spend more time appreciating the meal and less preoccupied with catching the right train. This is one scenario where randomness can provide a benefit. Taleb then discusses the differences between “satisficers” and “optimizers.” The commuter in the above example would be an optimizer. Satisficers, which Taleb discusses in Chapter 11, tend to be better able to find contentment in life. There is enough unpredictability built into their lives and they come to accept and even embrace it. For optimizers, the reverse is true. Taleb suggests that the more one aims at this organizing principle in their lives, one in which nothing but the most optimal situation will suffice, the more likely they are to experience unhappiness. Taleb examines some ways in which he is a satisficer, specifically his decision to do away with an alarm clock. He looks to build gray areas into his schedule rather than be entirely controlled by it. He sees a trend in current society, notably with children being raised to be optimizers as their parents cart them around from one activity to the next on a rigid schedule.

Taleb concludes by saying that he has tried to be concise enough in this section that an MBA would understand it. Borrowing from Rabbi Hillel, who was challenged to winnow his understanding of the Torah down to an axiom that a student standing on one leg would understand, Taleb states his own for the book: “We favor the visible, the embedded, the personal, the narrated, and the tangible; we scorn the abstract” (301).

Epilogue-Postscript Analysis

The Epilogue returns the reader to the story of Nero Tulip, the risk-averse trader from the book’s opening chapter. At the end of the Epilogue, Nero dies in a helicopter crash. He was the pilot. The anecdote shows that of all the things that cannot be predicted death is at the top of the list. Nero could have been better prepared for such an untimely death, but not immune from it happening. Taleb writes, “Nero’s excessive probability-consciousness in his profession somehow did not register fully into his treatment of physical risk” (291). Even as Nero was prepared to avoid such risky behavior as flying his own helicopter, he underestimated the role that randomness might have, thereby also underestimating the risk involved. Nero’s untimely end and his failure to foresee it despite his cautious personality show that the flaws Taleb has anatomized in human risk management and decision-making can never be fully overcome, due not only to the nature of our human brains but also to the nature of randomness itself.

In the postscript section, Taleb muses on a few addendums that he has after completing the drafting of the book. He returns to the attribution bias, this time to show a derivative of it which he calls the “inverse skills” problem. This speaks to the theme of The Distinction Between Luck and Skill. Taleb argues that generally, CEOs are primarily skilled at looking the part of a CEO. In contrast, Taleb says that professionals like cooks can be directly evaluated for their skills. He writes, “The degree of randomness in such an activity and our ability to isolate the contribution of the individual determine the visibility of the skills content. Accordingly, the cook at the company headquarters or the factory worker will exhibit their direct abilities with minimal uncertainty” (292-93). The position of CEO has no real equivalent because they are only evaluated by profit or lack thereof. Taleb further argues that “Lower-ranking persons in the enterprise are judged on both process and results—in fact, owing to the repetitive aspect of their efforts, their process converges rapidly to results. But top management is only paid on result—no matter the process” (293). Taleb also implies that because “The link between the skill of the CEO and the results of the company are tenuous” (294), the CEO has risen to the top because that person has benefited from luck; it is not necessarily skill that has landed them where they are. These final insights point to an important implication of Taleb’s book that he does not delve into: That although randomness and misperceptions of The Distinction Between Luck and Skill affect all people, their impact on a person’s life is significantly influenced by their class status. For a number of reasons, including the types of jobs they hold and their access to capital and support, adverse events and flawed perceptions of skill or cause can affect a working-class person differently and more negatively than a person with a white-collar job like a corporate executive. Thus, while randomness is by definition unbiased, it can contribute to perpetuating social inequality.

blurred text
blurred text
blurred text
blurred text